National Bank Act (1864)
Michael
P. Malloy
In
the 1830s the federal charter of the second Bank of the United States
expired. Until the early 1860s, the federal government had no direct
involvement in regulating U.S. banking. The national crisis of the
Civil War pushed the federal government to reenter bank regulation.
The war required vast amounts of money and credit, and difficulties
in financing the war were draining the nation's gold supply. As a
result, the gold standard, which gave value to the national currency,
was eventually abandoned. Borrowing from banks created under state
laws was one obvious source of needed credit. By 1861 there were
approximately 1,600 state-chartered banks, but no central bank system
(like the Federal Reserve) to monitor credit, and no banks directly
subject to federal supervision.
To
help finance the war, in 1861 Treasury Secretary Salmon P. Chase
recommended the establishment of a national banking system. National
banks could be chartered by the federal government and authorized to
issue bank notes secured by U.S. government bonds. Chase's plan would
have ensured a market for federal debt, since the new national banks
would be required to buy the bonds.
However,
the government first tried to finance the war directly by selling
U.S. notes to the public, without creating national banks. By early
1862, Congress had authorized the issuance of $150 million in U.S.
notes, the first of several issuances, but these sales did not
satisfy wartime credit needs. When Chase's next legislative effort,
the 1863 National Currency Act, did not solve the problem, it was
amended and reenacted as the National Bank Act (NBA) (13 Stat. 100)
in 1864, creating a national banking system on the model originally
proposed by Chase. The national bank system, which outlasted the
Civil War, became a central feature of the modern U.S. bank
regulatory system. It established the federal-state "dual
banking system" that has been a characteristic of U.S.
commercial banking ever since.
FEATURES
OF THE NBA
The
NBA created the position of the Comptroller of the Currency as an
office within the Treasury Department. The comptroller was authorized
to issue national bank charters in legislation that has remained
unchanged since 1864:
Associations for carrying on the business of banking ... may be formed by any number of natural persons, not less in any case than five. They shall enter into articles of association, which shall specify in general terms the object for which the association is formed.... These articles shall be signed by the persons uniting to form the association, and a copy of them shall be forwarded to the Comptroller of the Currency, to be filed and preserved in his office.
This
language guided the creation of such powerful nationwide banks as
Citibank and the Bank of America, as well as thousands of local
banks. The system was originally intended to create a mandatory
market for U.S. bonds, since each newly chartered national bank was
required to deliver to the comptroller government bonds in an amount
equal to $30,000 or one-third of its capital, whichever was greater.
However, long after this requirement was revoked in 1913, the role of
federally chartered national banks administered by the comptroller
has continued to be significant in the national economy.
COURT
CHALLENGES
As
part of Chase's plan for financing the war, the statutes passed
during the early 1860s imposed taxes on the capital and bank notes of
commercial banks, both state and national. With the tax on
state-chartered banks, Chase was attempting to encourage them to
convert to national charters. This plan was challenged in Veazie
Bank v. Fenno (1869),
in which Chase, by then Chief Justice of the Supreme Court, wrote the
majority opinion. The Court upheld the constitutionality of the tax,
but it did not directly address the constitutionality of the NBA to
grant banking charters.
That
issue was finally addressed in passing in Farmers'
& Mechanics' National Bank v. Dearing(1875).
The Supreme Court stated that the constitutionality of the NBA rested
"on the same principle as the act creating the second bank of
the United States." That principle was upheld under the
necessary and proper clause of Article I, section 8 of the
Constitution in McCulloch
v. Maryland (1819)
and Osborn
v. Bank of the United States (1824).
The validity of the NBA has been unchallenged since then.
FLEXIBLE
POWERS OF THE NATIONAL BANKS
Having
accepted the constitutionality of the NBA, the Court went on to
express the view that the national banks created under the act's
authority were to be somewhat favored, and this has largely been
their experience ever since. The national banking system now enjoys,
in addition to basic banking powers like lending and accepting
deposits, flexible power to engage in a broad range of other
activities, including data processing services, lease financing of
automobiles, municipal bond insurance, securities activities, and
selling variable annuities, among many others.
The
Office of the Comptroller, the oldest existing federal bank
regulator, is still a bureau of the Department of the Treasury. The
comptroller is responsible for administration of virtually all
federal laws applicable to national banks, including all banks
operating in the District of Columbia. The approval of the
comptroller is required for practically any significant action taken
by a national bank, including among other things chartering,
establishment of branches, and changes in corporate control or
structure. In addition, the comptroller has supervisory authority
over the day-to-day activities of national banks, including loan and
investment policies, trust activities, issuance of securities, and
the like. These supervisory responsibilities are carried out, for the
most part, through periodic on-site examinations of the banks by
national bank examiners. In addition, the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of
1999 requires the comptroller to supervise the "financial
services activities" of subsidiaries of national banks, the
privacy of nonpublic personal information of customers of national
banks, and consumer protection with respect to insurance sales by
national banks, among other things.
Courts
have generally treated the comptroller's decisions under the NBA and
other statutes as authoritative. In Camp
v. Pitts (1973),
the Supreme Court held that the comptroller's actions were subject to
a very limited standard of judicial review. This means that a party
seeking relief in court faces great difficulty, as that party must
meet very specific requirements to obtain a favorable ruling. This
limited standard, now the basic approach used in judicial review of
all federal bank regulators, has no doubt given the comptroller more
flexible power to encourage the growth of the national banking
system, without much judicial intervention.
See
also: Bank
of the United States; Federal Reserve Act.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Krooss,
H. E., ed. Documentary
History of Banking and Currency in the United States. New
York: Chelsea House Publishers, 1969.
Malloy,
Michael P., ed. Banking
and Financial Services Law: Cases, Materials, and Problems. Durham,
NC: Carolina Academic Press, 1999; suppl., 2002–2003.
Malloy,
Michael P. Banking
Law and Regulation. 3
vols. New York: Aspen Law and Business, 1994.
Malloy,
Michael P. Principals
of Bank Regulation. (Concise
HornBook Series) 2d ed. St. Paul, MN: West Group, 2003.
McCoy,
Patricia A., ed. Financial
Modernization After Gramm-Leach-Bliley. Newark,
NJ: Lexis-Nexis, 2002.
The
Gold Standard
During
the nineteenth century, U.S. currency was backed by both gold and
silver—in other words, a dollar in silver, nickel, or copper coins
or in paper money was guaranteed by the government to be convertible
into a dollar's worth of either metal. As a result of this
"bimetallic standard," the valuation of U.S. currency
fluctuated wildly. Because the value of the two metals on the open
market was constantly changing, speculators were able to turn a
profit by selling their coins for more than their face value when the
value of the metal exceeded its denomination. When the government
flooded the market with silver coins, the price of silver dropped,
citizens traded in their silver coins for gold, and federal gold
reserves were exhausted. At the same time, prices of wholesale and
retail goods saw a steady decline from the end of the Civil War
through the 1890s, sending farmers and other providers of goods,
whose fixed debts did not decline, into crisis. This chronic monetary
instability was a large factor in the 1896 election of President
William McKinley, who ran on a platform that included a change to a
gold standard. In 1900 McKinley signed the Gold Standard Act, making
gold reserves the basis of the monetary system. The gold standard
remained in effect until 1933, when the economic pressures of the
Great Depression—including gold-hoarding by a panicked
citizenry—led the United States to abandon it, and legislation was
passed that allowed the Federal Reserve to expand the supply of paper
money irrespective of gold reserves.
GET
OUT OF DEBT NOW! http://www.newdebtelimination.com
No comments:
Post a Comment